夜夜躁很很躁日日躁麻豆,精品人妻无码,制服丝袜国产精品,成人免费看www网址入口

網(wǎng)易首頁 > 網(wǎng)易號 > 正文 申請入駐

鮑威爾暗示降息,道指再創(chuàng)歷史新高(附杰克遜霍爾演講全文)

0
分享至

美聯(lián)儲主席鮑威爾(Jerome Powell)周五在懷俄明州杰克遜霍爾舉行的美聯(lián)儲年度會議上發(fā)表了備受期待的講話。他謹(jǐn)慎地釋放了未來可能降息的信號,同時強(qiáng)調(diào)高度的不確定性正使貨幣政策制定變得更加困難。

交易員目前預(yù)計(jì)9月美聯(lián)儲將降息的概率約為90%,而鮑威爾講話前這一概率為75%。交易員再次完全定價美聯(lián)儲年底前降息兩次。


鮑威爾在講話的書面稿中提到,稅收、貿(mào)易和移民政策的“重大變化”,導(dǎo)致美聯(lián)儲在實(shí)現(xiàn)“充分就業(yè)”和“物價穩(wěn)定”這雙重目標(biāo)之間的風(fēng)險平衡正在發(fā)生轉(zhuǎn)變。

他指出,雖然勞動力市場依然穩(wěn)健,經(jīng)濟(jì)展現(xiàn)出“韌性”,但下行風(fēng)險正在上升。同時,他警告稱,關(guān)稅增加帶來了新的通脹壓力,存在物價再次走高的風(fēng)險,而這可能導(dǎo)致美國陷入“滯脹”局面,這是美聯(lián)儲必須避免的情形。

在該聲明發(fā)表后,美股三大指數(shù)漲幅均超1.5%,道指再創(chuàng)新高;納斯達(dá)克中國金龍指數(shù)上漲2.73%。


鮑威爾強(qiáng)調(diào),與去年同一場合的講話相比,目前美聯(lián)儲基準(zhǔn)利率已經(jīng)低了一個百分點(diǎn),而失業(yè)率依然處在低位,這使得“我們能夠謹(jǐn)慎推進(jìn),逐步考慮調(diào)整政策立場。”

他補(bǔ)充說:“盡管如此,隨著政策處于限制性區(qū)間,基準(zhǔn)展望與風(fēng)險平衡的變化可能需要我們調(diào)整政策立場?!?/p>

這是他在講話中最接近“認(rèn)可降息”的表態(tài)。華爾街普遍認(rèn)為,美聯(lián)儲可能會在9月16日至17日舉行的聯(lián)邦公開市場委員會(FOMC)會議上宣布降息。除了市場預(yù)期,特朗普總統(tǒng)也多次公開猛烈批評鮑威爾和美聯(lián)儲,要求采取更激進(jìn)的降息措施。

自去年12月以來,美聯(lián)儲基準(zhǔn)利率一直維持在4.25%至4.5%的區(qū)間。政策制定者們多次強(qiáng)調(diào),關(guān)稅對通脹的影響充滿不確定性,因此需要謹(jǐn)慎行事。他們認(rèn)為,在當(dāng)前經(jīng)濟(jì)狀況與略微緊縮的政策立場下,美聯(lián)儲仍有時間來做進(jìn)一步?jīng)Q策。

雖然鮑威爾沒有直接回應(yīng)白宮關(guān)于降息的呼聲,但他強(qiáng)調(diào)了美聯(lián)儲獨(dú)立性的重要性?!癋OMC成員的決定將完全基于他們對數(shù)據(jù)的評估,以及這些數(shù)據(jù)對經(jīng)濟(jì)前景與風(fēng)險平衡的含義。我們絕不會偏離這一原則。”他說。

鮑威爾講話之際,白宮仍在與全球主要貿(mào)易伙伴進(jìn)行談判,局勢反復(fù)無常,前景并不明朗。最新數(shù)據(jù)顯示,美國消費(fèi)者物價逐漸走高,而批發(fā)價格的上升速度更快。

特朗普政府的立場是,關(guān)稅不會造成持久的通脹,因此應(yīng)當(dāng)降息。而鮑威爾在講話中則表示,未來可能出現(xiàn)多種結(jié)果,合理的基準(zhǔn)情境是關(guān)稅影響將是“短暫的,一次性的價格水平調(diào)整”,不足以成為長期維持高利率的理由。但他也承認(rèn),目前情況尚不確定。

“關(guān)稅上漲仍需要時間通過供應(yīng)鏈和分銷網(wǎng)絡(luò)傳導(dǎo)?!滨U威爾說,“此外,關(guān)稅稅率還在不斷變化,這可能會延長調(diào)整過程。”

// 五年政策框架回顧與教訓(xùn) //

除總結(jié)經(jīng)濟(jì)現(xiàn)狀與前景外,鮑威爾的講話還涉及美聯(lián)儲對政策框架的五年回顧。與上一次在2020年的審查相比,此次審查帶來了一些重要結(jié)論。

2020年特殊時期期間,美聯(lián)儲推出了“靈活平均通脹目標(biāo)”框架,允許通脹在2%目標(biāo)之上適度運(yùn)行,以彌補(bǔ)此前長期低于目標(biāo)的情況。其邏輯是,容忍稍高的通脹有助于確保就業(yè)市場更充分的復(fù)蘇。

然而,政策實(shí)施后不久,通脹急速攀升,最終達(dá)到40年來的最高水平,而美聯(lián)儲最初將其視為“暫時性”而未及時加息。鮑威爾承認(rèn),這一判斷失誤造成嚴(yán)重后果。

“事實(shí)證明,所謂的‘適度超調(diào)’完全沒有發(fā)生。幾個月后出現(xiàn)的通脹既不適度,也不是我們有意為之?!滨U威爾表示,“過去五年是一次痛苦的提醒:高通脹帶來的困境,對最無法承擔(dān)生活成本上漲的人群打擊最為沉重?!?/p>

在本次政策框架回顧中,美聯(lián)儲再次確認(rèn)將堅(jiān)持2%的長期通脹目標(biāo)。鮑威爾強(qiáng)調(diào):“我們認(rèn)為,堅(jiān)持這一目標(biāo)是維持長期通脹預(yù)期穩(wěn)定的關(guān)鍵因素?!?/p>

不過,圍繞這一目標(biāo)的爭論仍然存在。一些批評者認(rèn)為,2%的目標(biāo)過高,可能導(dǎo)致美元走弱;另一些人則呼吁美聯(lián)儲應(yīng)更靈活,以適應(yīng)經(jīng)濟(jì)變化。(據(jù)WIND)

鮑威爾講話全文:

August 22, 2025

Monetary Policy and the Fed’s Framework Review

Chair Jerome H. Powell

At “Labor Markets in Transition: Demographics, Productivity, and Macroeconomic Policy,” an economic symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole, Wyoming

Over the course of this year, the U.S. economy has shown resilience in a context of sweeping changes in economic policy. In terms of the Fed's dual-mandate goals, the labor market remains near maximum employment, and inflation, though still somewhat elevated, has come down a great deal from its post-pandemic highs. At the same time, the balance of risks appears to be shifting.

In my remarks today, I will first address the current economic situation and the near-term outlook for monetary policy. I will then turn to the results of our second public review of our monetary policy framework, as captured in the revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy that we released today.

Current Economic Conditions and Near-Term Outlook
When I appeared at this podium one year ago, the economy was at an inflection point. Our policy rate had stood at 5-1/4 to 5-1/2 percent for more than a year. That restrictive policy stance was appropriate to help bring down inflation and to foster a sustainable balance between aggregate demand and supply. Inflation had moved much closer to our objective, and the labor market had cooled from its formerly overheated state. Upside risks to inflation had diminished. But the unemployment rate had increased by almost a full percentage point, a development that historically has not occurred outside of recessions.1 Over the subsequent three Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meetings, we recalibrated our policy stance, setting the stage for the labor market to remain in balance near maximum employment over the past year (figure 1).


This year, the economy has faced new challenges. Significantly higher tariffs across our trading partners are remaking the global trading system. Tighter immigration policy has led to an abrupt slowdown in labor force growth. Over the longer run, changes in tax, spending, and regulatory policies may also have important implications for economic growth and productivity. There is significant uncertainty about where all of these polices will eventually settle and what their lasting effects on the economy will be.

Changes in trade and immigration policies are affecting both demand and supply. In this environment, distinguishing cyclical developments from trend, or structural, developments is difficult. This distinction is critical because monetary policy can work to stabilize cyclical fluctuations but can do little to alter structural changes.

The labor market is a case in point. The July employment report released earlier this month showed that payroll job growth slowed to an average pace of only 35,000 per month over the past three months, down from 168,000 per month during 2024 (figure 2).


2 This slowdown is much larger than assessed just a month ago, as the earlier figures for May and June were revised down substantially.3 But it does not appear that the slowdown in job growth has opened up a large margin of slack in the labor market—an outcome we want to avoid. The unemployment rate, while edging up in July, stands at a historically low level of 4.2 percent and has been broadly stable over the past year. Other indicators of labor market conditions are also little changed or have softened only modestly, including quits, layoffs, the ratio of vacancies to unemployment, and nominal wage growth. Labor supply has softened in line with demand, sharply lowering the "breakeven" rate of job creation needed to hold the unemployment rate constant. Indeed, labor force growth has slowed considerably this year with the sharp falloff in immigration, and the labor force participation rate has edged down in recent months.

Overall, while the labor market appears to be in balance, it is a curious kind of balance that results from a marked slowing in both the supply of and demand for workers. This unusual situation suggests that downside risks to employment are rising. And if those risks materialize, they can do so quickly in the form of sharply higher layoffs and rising unemployment.

At the same time, GDP growth has slowed notably in the first half of this year to a pace of 1.2 percent, roughly half the 2.5 percent pace in 2024 (figure 3). The decline in growth has largely reflected a slowdown in consumer spending. As with the labor market, some of the slowing in GDP likely reflects slower growth of supply or potential output.


Turning to inflation, higher tariffs have begun to push up prices in some categories of goods. Estimates based on the latest available data indicate that total PCE prices rose 2.6 percent over the 12 months ending in July. Excluding the volatile food and energy categories, core PCE prices rose 2.9 percent, above their level a year ago. Within core, prices of goods increased 1.1 percent over the past 12 months, a notable shift from the modest decline seen over the course of 2024. In contrast, housing services inflation remains on a downward trend, and nonhousing services inflation is still running at a level a bit above what has been historically consistent with 2 percent inflation (figure 4).4


The effects of tariffs on consumer prices are now clearly visible. We expect those effects to accumulate over coming months, with high uncertainty about timing and amounts. The question that matters for monetary policy is whether these price increases are likely to materially raise the risk of an ongoing inflation problem. A reasonable base case is that the effects will be relatively short lived—a one-time shift in the price level. Of course, "one-time" does not mean "all at once." It will continue to take time for tariff increases to work their way through supply chains and distribution networks. Moreover, tariff rates continue to evolve, potentially prolonging the adjustment process.

It is also possible, however, that the upward pressure on prices from tariffs could spur a more lasting inflation dynamic, and that is a risk to be assessed and managed. One possibility is that workers, who see their real incomes decline because of higher prices, demand and get higher wages from employers, setting off adverse wage–price dynamics. Given that the labor market is not particularly tight and faces increasing downside risks, that outcome does not seem likely.

Another possibility is that inflation expectations could move up, dragging actual inflation with them. Inflation has been above our target for more than four years and remains a prominent concern for households and businesses. Measures of longer-term inflation expectations, however, as reflected in market- and survey-based measures, appear to remain well anchored and consistent with our longer-run inflation objective of 2 percent.

Of course, we cannot take the stability of inflation expectations for granted. Come what may, we will not allow a one-time increase in the price level to become an ongoing inflation problem.

Putting the pieces together, what are the implications for monetary policy? In the near term, risks to inflation are tilted to the upside, and risks to employment to the downside—a challenging situation. When our goals are in tension like this, our framework calls for us to balance both sides of our dual mandate. Our policy rate is now 100 basis points closer to neutral than it was a year ago, and the stability of the unemployment rate and other labor market measures allows us to proceed carefully as we consider changes to our policy stance. Nonetheless, with policy in restrictive territory, the baseline outlook and the shifting balance of risks may warrant adjusting our policy stance.

Monetary policy is not on a preset course. FOMC members will make these decisions, based solely on their assessment of the data and its implications for the economic outlook and the balance of risks. We will never deviate from that approach.

Evolution of Monetary Policy Framework
Turning to my second topic, our monetary policy framework is built on the unchanging foundation of our mandate from Congress to foster maximum employment and stable prices for the American people. We remain fully committed to fulfilling our statutory mandate, and the revisions to our framework will support that mission across a broad range of economic conditions. Our revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy, which we refer to as our consensus statement, describes how we pursue our dual-mandate goals. It is designed to give the public a clear sense of how we think about monetary policy, and that understanding is important both for transparency and accountability, and for making monetary policy more effective.

The changes we made in this review are a natural progression, grounded in our ever-evolving understanding of our economy. We continue to build upon the initial consensus statement adopted in 2012 under Chair Ben Bernanke's leadership. Today's revised statement is the outcome of the second public review of our framework, which we conduct at five-year intervals.? This year's review included three elements: Fed Listens events at Reserve Banks around the country, a flagship research conference, and policymaker discussions and deliberations, supported by staff analysis, at a series of FOMC meetings.5

In approaching this year's review, a key objective has been to make sure that our framework is suitable across a broad range of economic conditions. At the same time, the framework needs to evolve with changes in the structure of the economy and our understanding of those changes. The Great Depression presented different challenges from those of the Great Inflation and the Great Moderation, which in turn are different from the ones we face today.6

At the time of the last review, we were living in a new normal, characterized by the proximity of interest rates to the effective lower bound (ELB), along with low growth, low inflation, and a very flat Phillips curve—meaning that inflation was not very responsive to slack in the economy.7 To me, a statistic that captures that era is that our policy rate was stuck at the ELB for seven long years following the onset of the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) in late 2008. Many here will recall the sluggish growth and painfully slow recovery of that era. It appeared highly likely that if the economy experienced even a mild downturn, our policy rate would be back at the ELB very quickly, probably for another extended period. Inflation and inflation expectations could then decline in a weak economy, raising real interest rates as nominal rates were pinned near zero. Higher real rates would further weigh on job growth and reinforce the downward pressure on inflation and inflation expectations, triggering an adverse dynamic.

The economic conditions that brought the policy rate to the ELB and drove the 2020 framework changes were thought to be rooted in slow-moving global factors that would persist for an extended period—and might well have done so, if not for the pandemic.8 The 2020 consensus statement included several features that addressed the ELB-related risks that had become increasingly prominent over the preceding two decades. We emphasized the importance of anchored longer-term inflation expectations to support both our price-stability and maximum-employment goals. Drawing on an extensive literature on strategies to mitigate risks associated with the ELB, we adopted flexible average inflation targeting—a "makeup" strategy to ensure that inflation expectations would remain well anchored even with the ELB constraint.9 In particular, we said that, following periods when inflation had been running persistently below 2 percent, appropriate monetary policy would likely aim to achieve inflation moderately above 2 percent for some time.

In the event, rather than low inflation and the ELB, the post-pandemic reopening brought the highest inflation in 40 years to economies around the world. Like most other central banks and private-sector analysts, through year-end 2021 we thought that inflation would subside fairly quickly without a sharp tightening in our policy stance (figure 5).10 When it became clear that this was not the case, we responded forcefully, raising our policy rate by 5.25 percentage points over 16 months. That action, combined with the unwinding of pandemic supply disruptions, contributed to inflation moving much closer to our target without the painful rise in unemployment that has accompanied previous efforts to counter high inflation.


Elements of the Revised Consensus Statement
This year's review considered how economic conditions have evolved over the past five years. During this period, we saw that the inflation situation can change rapidly in the face of large shocks. In addition, interest rates are now substantially higher than was the case during the era between the GFC and the pandemic. With inflation above target, our policy rate is restrictive—modestly so, in my view. We cannot say for certain where rates will settle out over the longer run, but their neutral level may now be higher than during the 2010s, reflecting changes in productivity, demographics, fiscal policy, and other factors that affect the balance between saving and investment (figure 6). During the review, we discussed how the 2020 statement's focus on the ELB may have complicated communications about our response to high inflation. We concluded that the emphasis on an overly specific set of economic conditions may have led to some confusion, and, as a result, we made several important changes to the consensus statement to reflect that insight.


First, we removed language indicating that the ELB was a defining feature of the economic landscape. Instead, we noted that our "monetary policy strategy is designed to promote maximum employment and stable prices across a broad range of economic conditions." The difficulty of operating near the ELB remains a potential concern, but it is not our primary focus. The revised statement reiterates that the Committee is prepared to use its full range of tools to achieve its maximum-employment and price-stability goals, particularly if the federal funds rate is constrained by the ELB.

Second, we returned to a framework of flexible inflation targeting and eliminated the "makeup" strategy. As it turned out, the idea of an intentional, moderate inflation overshoot had proved irrelevant. There was nothing intentional or moderate about the inflation that arrived a few months after we announced our 2020 changes to the consensus statement, as I acknowledged publicly in 2021.11

Well-anchored inflation expectations were critical to our success in bringing down inflation without a sharp increase in unemployment. Anchored expectations promote the return of inflation to target when adverse shocks drive inflation higher, and limit the risk of deflation when the economy weakens.12 Further, they allow monetary policy to support maximum employment in economic downturns without compromising price stability. Our revised statement emphasizes our commitment to act forcefully to ensure that longer-term inflation expectations remain well anchored, to the benefit of both sides of our dual mandate. It also notes that "price stability is essential for a sound and stable economy and supports the well-being of all Americans." This theme came through loud and clear at our Fed Listens events.13 The past five years have been a painful reminder of the hardship that high inflation imposes, especially on those least able to meet the higher costs of necessities.

Third, our 2020 statement said that we would mitigate "shortfalls," rather than "deviations," from maximum employment. The use of "shortfalls" reflected the insight that our real-time assessments of the natural rate of unemployment—and hence of "maximum employment"—are highly uncertain.14 The later years of the post-GFC recovery featured employment running for an extended period above mainstream estimates of its sustainable level, along with inflation running persistently below our 2 percent target. In the absence of inflationary pressures, it might not be necessary to tighten policy based solely on uncertain real-time estimates of the natural rate of unemployment.15

We still have that view, but our use of the term "shortfalls" was not always interpreted as intended, raising communications challenges. In particular, the use of "shortfalls" was not intended as a commitment to permanently forswear preemption or to ignore labor market tightness. Accordingly, we removed "shortfalls" from our statement. Instead, the revised document now states more precisely that "the Committee recognizes that employment may at times run above real-time assessments of maximum employment without necessarily creating risks to price stability." Of course, preemptive action would likely be warranted if tightness in the labor market or other factors pose risks to price stability.

The revised statement also notes that maximum employment is "the highest level of employment that can be achieved on a sustained basis in a context of price stability." This focus on promoting a strong labor market underscores the principle that "durably achieving maximum employment fosters broad-based economic opportunities and benefits for all Americans."The feedback we received at Fed Listens events reinforced the value of a strong labor market for American households, employers, and communities.

Fourth, consistent with the removal of "shortfalls," we made changes to clarify our approach in periods when our employment and inflation objectives are not complementary. In those circumstances, we will follow a balanced approach in promoting them. The revised statement now more closely aligns with the original 2012 language. We take into account the extent of departures from our goals and the potentially different time horizons over which each is projected to return to a level consistent with our dual mandate. These principles guide our policy decisions today, as they did over the 2022–24 period, when the departure from our 2 percent inflation target was the overriding concern.

In addition to these changes, there is a great deal of continuity with past statements. The document continues to explain how we interpret the mandate Congress has given us and describes the policy framework that we believe will best promote maximum employment and price stability. We continue to believe that monetary policy must be forward looking and consider the lags in its effects on the economy. For this reason, our policy actions depend on the economic outlook and the balance of risks to that outlook. We continue to believe that setting a numerical goal for employment is unwise, because the maximum level of employment is not directly measurable and changes over time for reasons unrelated to monetary policy.

We also continue to view a longer-run inflation rate of 2 percent as most consistent with our dual-mandate goals. We believe that our commitment to this target is a key factor helping keep longer-term inflation expectations well anchored. Experience has shown that 2 percent inflation is low enough to ensure that inflation is not a concern in household and business decisionmaking while also providing a central bank with some policy flexibility to provide accommodation during economic downturns.

Finally, the revised consensus statement retained our commitment to conduct a public review roughly every five years. There is nothing magic about a five-year pace. That frequency allows policymakers to reassess structural features of the economy and to engage with the public, practitioners, and academics on the performance of our framework. It is also consistent with several global peers.

Conclusion
In closing, I want to thank President Schmid and all his staff who work so diligently to host this outstanding event annually. Counting a couple of virtual appearances during the pandemic, this is the eighth time I have had the honor to speak from this podium. Each year, this symposium offers the opportunity for Federal Reserve leaders to hear ideas from leading economic thinkers and focus on the challenges we face. The Kansas City Fed was wise to lure Chair Volcker to this national park more than 40 years ago, and I am proud to be part of that tradition.

1. For example, after the July 2024 employment report, the 3-month average of the unemployment rate had increased more than 0.5 percentage point above its lowest value over the previous 12 months. For more information, see Claudia Sahm (2019), "Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals," in Heather Boushey, Ryan Nunn, and Jay Shambaugh, eds., Recession Ready: Fiscal Policies to Stabilize the American Economy (PDF) (Washington: Hamilton Project and Washington Center for Equitable Growth, May), pp. 67–92. Return to text

2. In early September, the Bureau of Labor Statistics will publish a preliminary estimate of benchmark revisions to the level of nonfarm payrolls as of March 2025, based on data from the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages. Data available to date suggest that the level of nonfarm payrolls will be revised down materially. The final benchmark revision will be incorporated into the monthly employment data in February 2026. Return to text

3. The total downward revision of 258,000 between May and June was spread across private-sector industries as well as state and local government employment, particularly education, and reflected both additional information from surveyed establishments and the re-estimation of seasonal factors. Return to text

4. Using the consumer price index and other information, an estimate of the contribution of housing services to 12-month core PCE inflation in July was 0.7 percentage point, while core services excluding housing contributed 2.0 percentage points. The contribution from each of these categories remains slightly above its average during the 2002–07 period, during which core PCE inflation averaged about 2 percent. In contrast, the contribution of core goods to 12-month core PCE inflation in July was about 0.25 percentage point, compared with the 2002–07 average of ?0.25 percentage point. Return to text

5. For more details, see the information available on the Board's website at https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-strategy-tools-and-communications-2025.htm. Return to text

6. See Jerome H. Powell (2019), "Challenges for Monetary Policy," speech delivered at "Challenges for Monetary Policy," a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, held in Jackson Hole, Wyo., August 23. Return to text

7. See Fran?ois Gourio, Benjamin K. Johannsen, and David López-Salido (2025), "The Origins, Structure, and Results of the Federal Reserve's 2019–20 Review of Its Monetary Policy Framework," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2025-065 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August). Return to text

8. A 2020 paper by Caldara and others discusses the structural factors behind the slow evolution of changes in the natural rate of unemployment, trend productivity growth, the natural rate of interest, and the slope of the Phillips curve; see Dario Caldara, Etienne Gagnon, Enrique Martínez-García, and Christopher J. Neely (2020), "Monetary Policy and Economic Performance since the Financial Crisis," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2020-065 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August). Return to text

9. See David Reifschneider and John C. Williams (2000), "Three Lessons for Monetary Policy in a Low-Inflation Era," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 32 (November), pp. 936–66; Michael T. Kiley and John M. Roberts (2017), "Monetary Policy in a Low Interest Rate World (PDF)," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, pp. 317–72; James Hebden, Edward P. Herbst, Jenny Tang, Giorgio Topa, and Fabian Winkler (2020), "How Robust Are Makeup Strategies to Key Alternative Assumptions?" Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2020-069 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August); and Ben S. Bernanke, Michael T. Kiley, and John M. Roberts (2019), "Monetary Policy Strategies for a Low-Rate Environment," AEA Papers and Proceedings, vol. 109 (May), pp. 421–26. On average inflation targeting, see Thomas M. Mertens and John C. Williams (2019), "Monetary Policy Frameworks and the Effective Lower Bound on Interest Rates," AEA Papers and Proceedings, vol. 109 (May), pp. 427–32. Return to text

10. See Ekaterina Peneva, Daniel Villar, and Jeremy Rudd (2025), "Retrospective on the Board Staff's Inflation Forecast Errors since 2019," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2025-069 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August). Return to text

11. See Ina Hajdini, Adam Shapiro, A. Lee Smith, and Daniel Villar (2025), "Inflation since the Pandemic: Lessons and Challenges," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2025-070 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August).

See also, for example, Jerome H. Powell (2021), "Transcript of Chair Powell's Press Conference (PDF)," December 15. Return to text

12. See Hess Chung, Callum Jones, Antoine Lepetit, and Fernando M. Martin (2025), "Implications of Inflation Dynamics for Monetary Policy Strategy," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2025-072 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August). Return to text

13. For additional information, see the report Fed Listens: Perspectives from the Public, which summarizes the 10 Fed Listens events hosted by the Board and the Federal Reserve Banks during 2025. Return to text

14. See Christopher Foote, Shigeru Fujita, Amanda Michaud, and Joshua Montes (2025), "Assessing Maximum Employment," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2025-067 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August). Return to text

15. See Brent Bundick, Isabel Cairó, and Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau (2025), "Labor Market Dynamics, Monetary Policy Tradeoffs, and a Shortfalls Approach to Pursuing Maximum Employment," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2025-068 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August). Return to text

FOMC長期目標(biāo)及貨幣政策策略更新聲明

August 22, 2025

Federal Open Market Committee announces approval of updates to its Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy

  • The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) on Friday announced the unanimous approval of updates to its Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy, which articulates the Committee's approach to monetary policy and serves as the foundation for its policy actions. The updated statement, also commonly known as the consensus statement, emphasizes that the FOMC's monetary policy strategy is designed to promote the congressionally-assigned goals of maximum employment and stable prices across a broad range of economic conditions for the benefit and well-being of all Americans.

The Committee first adopted a framework statement in 2012. The first public review of its framework took place in 2019-20, and the 2025 review was announced in November 2024. Today's updates reflect lessons from the economy over the past five years, and are intended to enhance the transparency, accountability, and effectiveness of monetary policy.

The 2025 review included Fed Listens events at Reserve Banks around the country and a research conference that was held in May. The Committee's two percent longer-run inflation goal was not a focus of the review.

— THE END —

特別聲明:以上內(nèi)容(如有圖片或視頻亦包括在內(nèi))為自媒體平臺“網(wǎng)易號”用戶上傳并發(fā)布,本平臺僅提供信息存儲服務(wù)。

Notice: The content above (including the pictures and videos if any) is uploaded and posted by a user of NetEase Hao, which is a social media platform and only provides information storage services.

相關(guān)推薦
熱點(diǎn)推薦
荷蘭慌了!安世中國有切割獨(dú)立跡象,中方定性,韓華集團(tuán)就是樣板

荷蘭慌了!安世中國有切割獨(dú)立跡象,中方定性,韓華集團(tuán)就是樣板

科普100克克
2025-10-19 21:03:44
萬科王石時代終局:自以為是教父,卻終究是投機(jī)者而非商業(yè)領(lǐng)袖

萬科王石時代終局:自以為是教父,卻終究是投機(jī)者而非商業(yè)領(lǐng)袖

風(fēng)向觀察
2025-10-19 23:10:10
央視曝光,日用品查出神經(jīng)毒素,檢出超90%,很多人現(xiàn)在還在用

央視曝光,日用品查出神經(jīng)毒素,檢出超90%,很多人現(xiàn)在還在用

禾寒?dāng)?/span>
2025-10-19 20:18:34
法官員證實(shí)盧浮宮遭搶劫:7分鐘9件拿破侖時期珠寶被盜

法官員證實(shí)盧浮宮遭搶劫:7分鐘9件拿破侖時期珠寶被盜

環(huán)球網(wǎng)資訊
2025-10-19 18:42:13
2-1!姆貝莫閃擊 加克波三中門柱 馬奎爾絕殺 曼聯(lián)送利物浦4連敗

2-1!姆貝莫閃擊 加克波三中門柱 馬奎爾絕殺 曼聯(lián)送利物浦4連敗

狍子歪解體壇
2025-10-20 01:29:23
《沉默的榮耀》大結(jié)局,人民網(wǎng)發(fā)文表揚(yáng),以后真不能再低估于和偉

《沉默的榮耀》大結(jié)局,人民網(wǎng)發(fā)文表揚(yáng),以后真不能再低估于和偉

嫹筆牂牂
2025-10-19 07:45:08
盜竊盧浮宮一共4人

盜竊盧浮宮一共4人

環(huán)球網(wǎng)資訊
2025-10-19 20:51:51
新郎跳河后續(xù):女方退18.8萬,不結(jié)婚原因曝光,男方家不打算追責(zé)

新郎跳河后續(xù):女方退18.8萬,不結(jié)婚原因曝光,男方家不打算追責(zé)

凡知
2025-10-19 12:00:55
軍委委員人數(shù)減少,有部門近兩年沒人擔(dān)任軍委委員,釋放什么信號

軍委委員人數(shù)減少,有部門近兩年沒人擔(dān)任軍委委員,釋放什么信號

李昕言溫度空間
2025-10-19 13:28:21
利物浦4連敗崩盤 連續(xù)3輪英超被絕殺 斯洛特用廢11.5億豪陣該下課

利物浦4連敗崩盤 連續(xù)3輪英超被絕殺 斯洛特用廢11.5億豪陣該下課

我愛英超
2025-10-20 01:40:15
5-0!3-0!亞洲四強(qiáng)驚艷世界杯:首輪3勝1平 中國女足創(chuàng)26年歷史

5-0!3-0!亞洲四強(qiáng)驚艷世界杯:首輪3勝1平 中國女足創(chuàng)26年歷史

侃球熊弟
2025-10-19 23:11:04
封鎖失敗?美稀土分離技術(shù)重大突破,2026年可擺脫稀土礦依賴

封鎖失???美稀土分離技術(shù)重大突破,2026年可擺脫稀土礦依賴

白夢日記
2025-10-18 20:12:22
上海專家發(fā)現(xiàn):吃甜食的老人,健康指數(shù)是吃蔬菜的人的8倍不止?

上海專家發(fā)現(xiàn):吃甜食的老人,健康指數(shù)是吃蔬菜的人的8倍不止?

霹靂炮
2025-10-17 21:31:29
暴雷!美國開始公開搶錢!

暴雷!美國開始公開搶錢!

龍浩觀天下
2025-10-18 17:02:00
現(xiàn)代版殺雞儆猴:不接受豁免,不開啟談判,直至將其徹底打服!

現(xiàn)代版殺雞儆猴:不接受豁免,不開啟談判,直至將其徹底打服!

李博世財經(jīng)
2025-10-19 17:20:57
徹底傻眼了,不僅廣西,全國都束手無策!

徹底傻眼了,不僅廣西,全國都束手無策!

另子維愛讀史
2025-10-19 11:44:19
西南聯(lián)大五大才子

西南聯(lián)大五大才子

祁州校尉
2025-10-19 14:23:07
真相追蹤!“野人小孩”的父親是一狗場的老板,母親是研究生學(xué)歷

真相追蹤!“野人小孩”的父親是一狗場的老板,母親是研究生學(xué)歷

火山詩話
2025-10-19 19:19:37
河北等多地天空現(xiàn)密集鳥群,網(wǎng)友擔(dān)心是災(zāi)害預(yù)兆,當(dāng)?shù)胤Q未收到相關(guān)預(yù)警,專家解讀

河北等多地天空現(xiàn)密集鳥群,網(wǎng)友擔(dān)心是災(zāi)害預(yù)兆,當(dāng)?shù)胤Q未收到相關(guān)預(yù)警,專家解讀

瀟湘晨報
2025-10-19 17:54:12
楊振寧一生最大的遺憾:年薪10000美元,卻沒來得及借錢給杜致仁

楊振寧一生最大的遺憾:年薪10000美元,卻沒來得及借錢給杜致仁

不系之舟225
2025-10-19 19:19:46
2025-10-20 06:12:49
紫京投研 incentive-icons
紫京投研
財富創(chuàng)造自由
662文章數(shù) 1088關(guān)注度
往期回顧 全部

財經(jīng)要聞

星巴克中國股權(quán)出售進(jìn)入倒計(jì)時

頭條要聞

澤連斯基:愿意參加特朗普與普京在匈牙利的會晤

頭條要聞

澤連斯基:愿意參加特朗普與普京在匈牙利的會晤

體育要聞

正在爆火的"拼好球" 馬斯克和樊振東也在玩

娛樂要聞

竇驍婚變升級!何超蓮被曝已有新歡

科技要聞

獨(dú)家|楊振寧:最頂尖的學(xué)生不是教出來的

汽車要聞

最高15000元兜底 智界R7/S7推出購置稅補(bǔ)貼方案

態(tài)度原創(chuàng)

藝術(shù)
時尚
旅游
健康
游戲

藝術(shù)要聞

故宮珍藏的墨跡《十七帖》,比拓本更精良,這才是地道的魏晉寫法

真有品味的中年女人,穿衣打扮都有這4個共同點(diǎn),你中了嗎?

旅游要聞

熱聞|清明假期將至,熱門目的地有哪些?

內(nèi)分泌科專家破解身高八大謠言

《寶可夢Z-A》M站玩家評分降至4.3!外媒開始盼續(xù)作

無障礙瀏覽 進(jìn)入關(guān)懷版 六月婷婷婷婷婷婷婷| 91精品人妻中文字幕色| 无码人妻一区在线| 日本99久久久久久久久人妻斩| 欧美精品亚洲精品日韩专| 日韩av人人夜夜澡人人爽| 狂野欧美性猛交XXXX巴西| 国产精品久精品毛片| 99久久精品免费看国产| 欧美老妇配少牲交| 精品一卡2卡三卡4卡乱码精品视频| 亚洲AV秘 无码一区二区久久| 久久精品国产精品国产一区| 毛片色偷拍免费观看| 欧美成a网| 黄色网视毛片视频网站| 色中色综合网| 精品不卡一区二区| 亚洲成人手机在线| 在线观看亚洲网站4444| 国产淫荡小视频| 国内无遮码无码| 国产精品剧情一区二区三区| 欧美乱伦视频网站| 亚洲国产成人a精品不卡在线| 国产精品久久久久久久久夜色| 黑人巨茎大战白人美女| 亚洲精品NV久久久久久久久久| 亚洲精品无码国产片| 超级刺激毛片免费看| 日本XXXX18野外无毒不卡| 国产人妻人伦精品婷婷| 久热这里有精品免费视频| 国产免费av片在线观看| 成人午夜福利视频后入| 无套内谢孕妇毛片免费看 | 亚洲天天影院色香欲综合| 色色一区二区三区| 国产老熟女wasnt| 国产精品大尺度尺度视频| 日本性爱小视频|